r/AskHistorians • u/[deleted] • Nov 24 '15
How much of a financial burden was the Jizya on non-Muslims?
Hello, I'm curious to know how much of a financial burden the Jizya, the tax levied on non-Muslims in Muslim areas, was on the common people, and by extension whether it was enough of a burden to compel people to convert.
I was mostly curious about during the original Muslim conquests during the time of Muhammad and the years following, but I would also be interested in information during other periods, such as the Golden Age of Islam or the Ottoman Empire.
Thank you.
27
Nov 24 '15
To add to this: I heard somewhere that the Jizya was a replacement for the Zakat - or the alms giving required of Muslims as one of the Five Pillars. I also understand that this interpretation is debated among Islamic scholars and scholars of Islam. Can anyone shed light on this? Especially on the amounts as they compared to each other?
-1
36
u/sunagainstgold Medieval & Earliest Modern Europe Nov 25 '15 edited Nov 25 '15
As you suspect, the answer depends on the time and place, but frequently also on the economic status of the dhimmi being taxed. It's important to keep in mind that jizya (and its equivalent in Christian lands!) was just one of a range of economic (and of course other types of) restrictions applied to dhimmi populations, so it's very hard to isolate the impact of just the jizya.
Nevertheless, we can see an interesting pattern emerge. Richard Bulliet has argued based on studies of naming patterns for a logarithmic-type conversion to Islam: initially slow, then increasing at an increasing rate, then slowing down, finally just a trickle as only the real diehards remain (or all the diehards have emigrated). This pattern frequently fits well to the arrival of Islam in new regions--often mirroring the establishment of better infrastructure for tax collection or the rise of a new dynasty that brings its own harsher measures, or turmoil that causes worse economic conditions for Muslims and dhimmis alike. (Which would make paying even more even less attractive.)
In Palestine, for example, the Umayyad caliphate conquering the territory was more interested in rule than conversion. Preferring that cities surrender peacefully, they negotiated terms of surrender that provided religious freedom. And we see that the jizya in these cases was rather light.
Under the Abbasids, however, there was significant political turmoil in the region resulting in already-bad economic circumstances, increasing taxes on everyone already. The extra burden in already-bad times led to more conversion. And when individual rebel groups or governors would desire conversion, we know persecutions like loading people into prison to starve them until they converted, were accompanied by extra economic burdens. For example, Jews in Samaria in the 9th century had to pay a harsh fee to circumcise their sons, an absolute requirement in Judaism.
A major boost towards conversion efforts occurred across the Islamic world in the 12th-13th centuries. Forced conversion of Jews in particular by the Almoravids and Almohads in North Africa and Iberia in the west accompanied increased economic burdens in the east--but also, as 12th century Syrian jurist al-Shayzari tells us, ritualistic aspects surrounding tax collection to cause humiliation:
Unsurprisingly, this era sees both increasing complaints in Jewish letters from across the Mediterranean about the harsh economic burden of the jizya--and cases of mass conversion to Islam in the Near East.
In Muslim Sicily, the economic burden ramped up with increasing organization and bureaucratization of the ruling class, mirroring patterns of emigration off Sicily, fleeing to areas not yet controlled by Muslims, and conversion. Under the Aghlabids, jizya was just levied on communities instead of individuals. This probably helped remove one of the jizya's major tactics: disproportionate impact on the poor.
Additionally, the Aghlabids didn't apply restrictions uniformly to dhimmi-owned land (although this could be for any number of reasons, not just lack of uniform organization). Some dhimmis were banned from selling their land, and some weren't. Conversion to Islam would instantly lift that restriction, making it an extremely attractive prospect for someone interested in or needing a liquid asset for whatever reason.
But with the brief period of Fatimid rule and the later heirs of its bureaucracy, the jizya was levied more uniformly and harshly, according to the Jewish documents concerning Sicily preserved in the Cairo Geniza.
In al-Andalus (Iberia), the conquering Umayyads applied the jizya strategically with respect to the Christian former aristocracy. They wanted to keep the tax burden heavy enough for them to profit, but light enough to keep profiting. Keeping the former nobility Christian, of course, also allowed the Muslim rulers to keep what could be a troublesome element of the population under more restrictions than they could otherwise justify.
It's also significant in terms of judging the harshness of the jizya, I think, that various dhimmi communities developed strategies to offset its impact. For example, the disproportionate effect on the poor, which al-Shayzari also discusses (for his specific time and place, of course).
The Jewish community in Cairo, as Mark Cohen has so clearly illustrated, banded together and had its elite donate money to a central pool to distribute to the poor. This was earmarked for paying the cash jizya tax. (They had organized other types of collective charity, too.)
In Sicily, monasteries initially served as mediators between the Greek Christian population and their Muslim rulers--a factor in/a result of the jizya's communal application. This blunted the potentially humiliating interactions and allowed a communal response to offset the extra burden on the poor. With the arrival of the Fatimids, the increasing jizya and other restrictions, Christian leaders started fleeing the island in increasing numbers. This re-opened the vulnerability of the population, consequently, burdens and conversions increased.
So by the high Middle Ages, yes, we have sources that directly say the jizya was a problem. We can see its effects both then and earlier. Frequently, a harsher jizya was accompanied by other restrictions. Was the goal conversion to Islam? In some cases it does appear to be used strategically. But we also see the development of institutions to deal with the increased burden among dhimmi populations determined to hold on to their religion.